An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations - Adam Smith (ebooks children's books free .TXT) 📗
- Author: Adam Smith
- Performer: 0226763749
Book online «An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations - Adam Smith (ebooks children's books free .TXT) 📗». Author Adam Smith
process is decided and not till it is decided ; there seems to be
no more danger of corruption than when such fees are prohibited
altogether. Those fees, without occasioning any considerable
increase in the expense of a law-suit, might be rendered fully
sufficient for defraying the whole expense of justice. But
not being paid to the judges till the process was determined,
they might be some incitement to the diligence of the court in
examining and deciding it. In courts which consisted of a
considerable number of judges, by proportioning the share of each
judge to the number of hours and days which he had employed in
examining the process, either in the court, or in a committee, by
order of the court, those fees might give some encouragement to
the diligence of each particular judge. Public services are never
better performed, than when their reward comes only in
consequence of their being performed, and is proportioned to the
diligence employed in performing them. In the different
parliaments of France, the fees of court (called epices and
vacations) constitute the far greater part of the emoluments of
the judges. After all deductions are made, the neat salary paid
by the crown to a counsellor or judge in the parliament of
Thoulouse. in rank and dignity the second parliament of the
kingdom, amounts only to 150 livres, about �6:11s. sterling
a-year. About seven years ago, that sum was in the same place the
ordinary yearly wages of a common footman. The distribuion of
these epices, too, is according to the diligence of the judges. A
diligent judge gains a comfortable, though moderate revenue, by
his office; an idle one gets little more than his salary.
Those parliaments are, perhaps, in many respects, not very
convenient courts of justice; but they have never been accused ;
they seem never even to have been suspected of corruption.
The fees of court seem originaliy to have been the principal
support of the different courts of justice in England. Each
court endeavoured to draw to itself as much business as it could,
and was, upon that account, willing to take cognizance of many
suits which were not originally intended to fall under its
jurisdiction. The court of king’s bench, instituted for the trial
of criminal causes only, took cognizance of civil suits; the
plaintiff pretending that the defendant, in not doing him
justice, had been guilty of some trespass or misdemeanour. The
court of exchequer, instituted for the levying of the king’s
revenue, and for enforcing the payment of such debts only as were
due to the king, took cognizance of all other contract debts ;
the plantiff alleging that he could not pay the king, because the
defendant would not pay him. In consequence of such fictions, it
came, in many cases, to depend altogether upon the parties,
before what court they would choose to have their cause tried,
and each court endeavoured, by superior dispatch and
impartiality, to draw to itself as many causes as it could. The
present admirable constitution of the courts of justice in
England was, perhaps, originally, in a great measure, formed by
this emulation, which anciently took place between their
respective judges : each judge endeavouring to give, in his own
court, the speediest and most effectual remedy which the law
would admit, for every sort of injustice. Originally, the courts
of law gave damages only for breach of contract. The court of
chancery, as a court of conscience, first took upon it to enforce
the specific performance of agreements. When the breach of
contract consisted in the non-payment of money, the damage
sustained could be compensated in no other way than by ordering
payment, which was equivalent to a specific performance of the
agreement. In such cases, therefore, the remedy of the courts
of law was sufficient. It was not so in others. When the
tenant sued his lord for having unjustly outed him of his lease,
the damages which he recovered were by no means equivalent to the
possession of the land. Such causes, therefore, for some time,
went all to the court of chancery, to the no small loss of the
courts of law. It was to draw back such causes to themselves,
that the courts of law are said to have invented the artificial
and fictitious writ of ejectment, the most effectual remedy for
an unjust outer or dispossession of land.
A stamp-duty upon the law proceedings of each particular court,
to be levied by that court, and applied towards the maintenance
of the judges, and other officers belonging to it, might in the
same manner, afford a revenue sufficient for defraying the
expense of the administration of justice, without bringing any
burden upon the general revenue of the society. The judges,
indeed, might in this case, be under the temptation of
multiplying unnecessarily the proceedings upon every cause, in
order to increase, as much as possible, the produce of such a
stamp-duty. It has been the custom in modern Europe to regulate,
upon most occasions, the payment of the attorneys and clerks of
court according to the number of pages which they had occasion to
write; the court, however, requiring that each page should
contain so many lines, and each line so many words. In order to
increase their payment, the attorneys and clerks have contrived
to multiply words beyond all necessity, to the corruption of the
law language of, I believe, every court of justice in Europe.
A like temptation might, perhaps, occasion a like corruption in
the form of law proceedings.
But whether the administration of justice be so contrived as to
defray its own expense, or whether the judges be maintained by
fixed salaries paid to them from some other fund, it does not
seen necessary that the person or persons entrusted with the
executive power should be charged with the management of that
fund, or with the payment of those salaries. That fund might
arise from the rent of landed estates, the management of each
estate being entrusted to the particular court which was to be
maintained by it. That fund might arise even from the
interest of a sum of money, the lending out of which might, in
the same manner, be entrusted to the court which was to be
maintained by it. A part, though indeed but a small part of the
salary of the judges of the court of session in Scotland, arises
from the interest of a sum of money. The necessary instability of
such a fund seems, however, to render it an improper one for the
maintenance of an institution which ought to last for ever.
The separation of the judicial from the executive power, seems
originally to have arisen from the increasing business of the
society, in consequence of its increasing improvement. The
administration of justice became so laborious and so complicated
a duty, as to require the undivided attention of the person to
whom it was entrusted. The person entrusted with the executive
power, not having leisure to attend to the decision of private
causes himself, a deputy was appointed to decide them in his
stead. In the progress of the Roman greatness, the consul was too
much occupied with the political affairs of the state, to attend
to the administration of justice. A praetor, therefore, was
appointed to administer it in his stead. In the progress of the
European monarchies, which were founded upon the ruins of the
Roman empire, the sovereigns and the great lords came universally
to consider the administration of justice as an office both too
laborious and too ignoble for them to execute in their own
persons. They universally, therefore, discharged themselves of
it, by appointing a deputy, bailiff or judge.
When the judicial is united to the executive power, it is scarce
possible that justice should not frequently be sacrificed to what
is vulgarly called politics. The persons entrusted with the
great interests of the state may even without any corrupt views,
sometimes imagine it necessary to sacrifice to those interests
the rights of a private man. But upon the impartial
administration of justice depends the liberty of every
individual, the sense which he has of his own security. In order
to make every individual feel himself perfectly secure in the
possession of every right which belongs to him, it is not only
necessary that the judicial should be separated from the
executive power, but that it should be rendered as much as
possible independent of that power. The judge should not be
liable to be removed from his office according to the caprice of
that power. The regular payment of his salary should not depend
upon the good will, or even upon the good economy of that power.
PART III.
Of the Expense of public Works and public Institutions.
The third and last duty of the sovereign or commonwealth, is that
of erecting and maintaining those public institutions and those
public works, which though they may be in the highest degree
advantageous to a great society, are, however, of such a nature,
that the profit could never repay the expense to any individual,
or small number of individuals; and which it, therefore, cannot
be expected that any individual, or small number of individuals,
should erect or maintain. The performance of this duty requires,
too, very different degrees of expense in the different periods
of society.
After the public institutions and public works necessary for the
defence of the socicty, and for the administration of justice,
both of which have already been mentioned, the other works and
institutions of this kind are chiefly for facilitating the
commerce of the society, and those for promoting the instruction
of the people. The institutions for instruction are of two kinds:
those for the education of the youth, and those for the
instruction of people of all ages. The consideration of the
manner in which the expense of those different sorts of public
works and institutions may be most properly defrayed will divide
this third part of the present chapter into three different
articles.
ARTICLE I. - Of the public Works and Institutions for
facilitating the Commerce of the Society.
And, first, of those which are necessary for facilitating
Commerce in general.
That the erection and maintenance of the public works which
facilitate the commerce of any country, such as good roads,
bridges, navigable canals, harbours, etc. must require very
different degrees of expense in the different periods of society,
is evident without any proof. The expense of making and
maintaining the public roads of any country must evidently
increase with the annual produce of the land and labour of that
country, or with the quantity and weight of the goods which it
becomes necessary to fetch and carry upon those roads. The
strength of a bridge must be suited to the number and weight of
the carriages which are likely to pass over it. The depth and the
supply of water for a navigable canal must be proportioned to the
number and tonnage of the lighters which are likely to carry
goods upon it; the extent of a harbour, to the number of the
shipping which are likely to take shelter in it.
It does not seem necessary that the expense of those public works
should be defrayed from that public revenue, as it is commonly
called, of which the collection and application are in most
countries, assigned to the executive power. The greater part of
such public works may easily be so managed, as to afford a
particular revenue, sufficient for defraying their own expense
without bringing any burden upon the general revenue of the
society.
A highway, a bridge, a navigable canal, for example, may, in most
cases, be both made add maintained by a small toll upon the
carriages which make use
Comments (0)