An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations - Adam Smith (ebooks children's books free .TXT) 📗
- Author: Adam Smith
- Performer: 0226763749
Book online «An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations - Adam Smith (ebooks children's books free .TXT) 📗». Author Adam Smith
certain and not arbitrary. The time of payment, the manner of
payment, the quantity to be paid, ought all to be clear and plain
to the contributor, and to every other person. Where it is
otherwise, every person subject to the tax is put more or less in
the power of the tax-gatherer, who can either aggravate the tax
upon any obnoxious contributor, or extort, by the terror of such
aggravation, some present or perquisite to himself. The
uncertainty of taxation encourages the insolence, and favours the
corruption, of an order of men who are naturally unpopular, even
where they are neither insolent nor corrupt. The certainty of
what each individual ought to pay is, in taxation, a matter of so
great importance, that a very considerable degree of inequality,
it appears, I believe, from the experience of all nations, is not
near so great an evil as a very small degree of uncertainty.
3. Every tax ought to be levied at the time, or in the manner, in
which it is most likely to be convenient for the contributor to
pay it. A tax upon the rent of land or of houses, payable at the
same term at which such rents are usually paid, is levied at the
time when it is most likely to be convenient for the contributor
to pay ; or when he is most likely to have wherewithall to pay.
Taxes upon such consumable goods as are articles of luxury, are
all finally paid by the consumer, and generally in a manner that
is very convenient for him. He pays them by little and little, as
he has occasion to buy the goods. As he is at liberty too, either
to buy or not to buy, as he pleases, it must be his own fault if
he ever suffers any considerable inconveniecy from such taxes.
4. Every tax ought to be so contrived, as both to take out and to
keep out of the pockets of the people as little as possible, over
and above what it brings into the public treasury of the state. A
tax may either take out or keep out of the pockets of the people
a great deal more than it brings into the public treasury, in the
four following ways. First, the levying of it may require a great
number of officers, whose salaries may eat up the greater part of
the produce of the tax, and whose perquisites may impose another
additional tax upon the people. Secondly, it may obstruct the
industry of the people, and discourage them from applying to
certain branches of business which might give maintenance and
employment to great multitudes. While it obliges the people
to pay, it may thus diminish, or perhaps destroy, some of the
funds which might enable them more easily to do so. Thirdly, by
the forfeitures and other penalties which those unfortunate
individuals incur, who attempt unsuccessfully to evade the tax,
it may frequently ruin them, and thereby put an end to the
benefit which the community might have received from the
employment of their capitals. An injudicious tax offers a great
temptation to smuggling. But the penalties of smuggling must
arise in proportion to the temptation. The law, contrary to all
the ordinary principles of justice, first creates the temptation,
and then punishes those who yield to it; and it commonly enhances
the punishment, too, in proportion to the very circumstance which
ought certainly to alleviate it, the temptation to commit the
crime.{ See Sketches of the History of Man page 474, and Seq.}
Fourthly, by subjecting the people to the frequent visits and the
odious examination of the tax-gatherers, it may expose them to
much unnecessary trouble, vexation, and oppression ; and though
vexation is not, strictly speaking, expense, it is certainly
equivalent to the expense at which every man would be willing to
redeem himself from it. It is in some one or other of these four
different ways, that taxes are frequently so much more burdensome
to the people than they are beneficial to the sovereign.
The evident justice and utility of the foregoing maxims have
recommended them, more or less, to the attention of all nations.
All nations have endeavoured, to the best of their judgment, to
render their taxes as equal as they could contrive ; as certain,
as convenient to the contributor, both the time and the mode of
payment, and in proportion to the revenue which they brought to
the prince, as little burdensome to the people. The following
short review of some of the principal taxes which have taken
place in different ages and countries, will show, that the
endeavours of all nations have not in this respect been equally
successful.
ARTICLE I. � Taxes upon Rent � Taxes upon the Rent of Land.
A tax upon the rent of land may either be imposed according to a
certain canon, every district being valued at a curtain rent,
which valuation is not afterwards to be altered; or it may be
imposed in such a manner, as to vary with every variation in the
real rent of the land, and to rise or fall with the improvement
or declension of its cultivation.
A land tax which, like that of Great Britain, is assessed upon
each district according to a certain invariable canon, though it
should be equal at the time of its first establishment,
necessarily becomes unequal in process of time, according to the
unequal degrees of improvement or neglect in the cultivation of
the different parts of the country. In England, the valuation,
according to which the different counties and parishes were
assessed to the land tax by the 4th of William and Mary, was very
unequal even at its first establishment. This tax, therefore, so
far offends against the first of the four maxims above mentioned.
It is perfectly agreeable to the other three. It is perfectly
certain. The time of payment for the tax, being the same as that
for the rent, is as convenient as it can be to the contributor.
Though the landlord is, in all cases, the real contributor, the
tax is commonly advanced by the tenant, to whom the landlord is
obliged to allow it in the payment of the rent. This tax is
levied by a much smaller number of officers than any other which
affords nearly the same revenue. As the tax upon each district
does not rise with the rise of the rent, the sovereign does not
share in the profits of the landlord’s improvements. Those
improvements sometimes contribute, indeed, to the discharge of
the other landlords of the district. But the aggravation of the
tax, which this may sometimes occasion upon a particular estate,
is always so very small, that it never can discourage those
improvements, nor keep down the produce of the land below what it
would otherwise rise to. As it has no tendency to diminish the
quantity, it can have none to raise the price of that produce.
It does not obstruct the industry of the people; it subjects the
landlord to no other inconveniency besides the unavoidable one of
paying the tax.
The advantage, however, which the landlord has derived from the
invariable constancy of the valuation. by which all the lands of
Great Britain are rated to the land-tax, has been principally
owing to some circumstances altogether extraneous to the nature
of the tax
It has been owing in part, to the great prosperity of almost
every part of the country, the rents of almost all the estates of
Great Britain having, since the time when this valuation was
first established, been continually rising, and scarce any of
them having fallen. The landlords, therefore, have almost all
gained the difference between the tax which they would have paid,
according to the present rent of their estates, and that which
they actually pay according to the ancient valuation. Had the
state of the country been different, had rents been gradually
falling in consequence of the declension of cultivation, the
landlords would almost all have lost this difference. In the
state of things which has happened to take place since the
revolution, the constancy of the valuation has been advantageous
to the landlord and hurtful to the sovereign. In a different
state of things it might have been advantageous to the sovereign
and hurtful to the landlord.
As the tax is made payable in money, so the valuation of the land
is expressed in money. Since the establishment of this valuation,
the value of silver has been pretty uniform, and there has been
no alteration in the standard of the coin, either as to weight or
fineness. Had silver risen considerably in its value, as it seems
to have done in the course of the two centuries which preceded
the discovery of the mines of America, the constancy of the
valuation might have proved very oppressive to the landlord. Had
silver fallen considerably in its value, as it certainly did for
about a century at least after the discovery of those mines, the
same constancy of valuation would have reduced very much this
branch of the revenue of the sovereign. Had any considerable
alteration been made in the standard of the money, either by
sinking the same quantity of silver to a lower denomination, or
by raising it to a higher ; had an ounce of silver, for example,
instead of being coined into five shillings and two pence, been
coined either into pieces which bore so low a denomination as two
shillings and seven pence, or into pieces which bore so high a
one as ten shillings and four pence, it would, in the one case,
have hurt the revenue of the proprietor, in the other that of the
sovereign.
In circumstances, therefore, somewhat different from those which
have actually taken place, this constancy of valuation might have
been a very great inconveniency, either to the contributors or to
the commonwealth. In the course of ages, such circumstances,
however, must at some time or other happen. But though empires,
like all the other works of men, have all hitherto proved mortal,
yet every empire aims at immortality. Every constitution,
therefore, which it is meant should be as permanent as the empire
itseif, ought to be convenient, not in certain circumstances
only, but in all circumstances; or ought to be suited, not to
those circumstances which are transitory, occasional, or
accidental, but to those which are necessary, and therefore
always the same.
A tax upon the rent of land, which varies with every variation of
the rent, or which rises and falls according to the improvement
or neglect of cultivation, is recommended by that sect of men of
letters in France, who call themselves the economists, as the
most equitable of all taxes. All taxes, they pretend, fall
ultimately upon the rent of land, and ought, therefore, to be
imposed equally upon the fund which must finally pay them. That
all taxes ought to fall as equally as possible upon the fund
which must finally pay them, is certainly true. But without
entering into the disagreeable discussion of the metaphysical
arguments by which they support their very ingenious theory, it
will sufficiently appear, from the following review, what are the
taxes which fall finally upon the rent of the land, and what are
those which fall finally upon some other fund.
In the Venetian territory, all the arable lands which are given
in lease to farmers are taxed at a tenth of the rent. { Memoires
concernant les Droits, p. 240, 241.} The leases are recorded in a
public register, which is kept by the officers of revenue in each
province or district. When the proprietor cultivates his own
lands, they are valued according to an equitable estimation, and
he is allowed a
Comments (0)